Robert B. Ekelund, Jr. y Edward O.
Price III publicaron The Economics of Edwin Chadwick: Incentives Matter, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 2012. La reseña de la obra para EH.Net preparada por John D.
Singleton, (del Departmento de Economía de Duke University, coeditor con J.
Daniel Hammond y Steven G. Medema of
/Chicago Price Theory/ (Edward Elgar, 2013)
y autor de “‘Money is a Sterile Thing’: Martin Luther on the Immorality of Usury Reconsidered,” /History
of Political Economy/, 2011), señala: “To the extent that Edwin Chadwick is
known to historians of economics, Robert
Ekelund (Professor Emeritus in
Economics at Auburn University) and Edward
Price (Professor Emeritus at Oklahoma State University) have helped
inform this awareness through a number
of articles over the past 35 years. /The
Economics of Edwin Chadwick: Incentives Matter/ collects these insights
and aims to establish Chadwick’s import,
both within classical economics and to modern
economics. The book therefore combines exposition Chadwick’s writings and interpretation in modern terms
and frameworks with comparisons to
contemporary analysis and evaluation. Interested readers will discover an engaging and frequently thoughtful
examination of Edwin Chadwick’s economics.
The book is organized into three
parts totaling nine chapters. The first,
“Who Was Edwin Chadwick?” provides an introduction and useful biographical sketch of Chadwick’s life, while
the second chapter presents the book’s
overriding theme: Chadwick’s modernity. Two parts, “The
Regulation of Markets” and “Law, Sociology, and Economics,” structure the discussions of the numerous areas to which Chadwick applied his economic analysis. His contributions in the areas of competitive bidding for exclusive contracts, the railways, funeral and burial markets, education, business cycles, criminal justice, sanitation and others are reviewed in turn. The final chapter offers the authors’ reflections on Chadwick’s relevance for contemporary society.
Ekelund and Price argue throughout that “cases and abstractions from the writings of Edwin Chadwick show that ... he brought modern economics to the table in evaluating markets, public policy, and (what he believed to be) the appropriate division of roles between government and the private sector” (p. 45). Although this statement provokes ruminations about what “modern”
subsumes and what it means for an eighteenth-century writer to be so, the authors do not indulge these. They apply modernity to mean Chadwick’s “use of concepts such as the ‘common pool,’ time and opportunity costs, the demand curve, marginal analysis, strategic behavior, public choice, implicit markets (as for ‘accidents’), property rights and liability assignment” (p. 45). An additional aspect of the authors’ claim is Chadwick’s marshaling of statistics to support his recommendations: “Chadwick stands out as a pioneer in the science that requires evidence for reasoning and conclusions regarding economic and social policy” (p. 44). The chapter detailing Chadwick’s analysis of the railways provides an illustrative example. Chadwick contended that the rail system of England was fraught with inefficiencies, such as monopoly, fragmentation, and waste, and supported nationalization. In making this argument, he offered statistics that compared costs and performance across six European countries which showed prices and the degree of price discrimination in England to be the highest. “According to Chadwick, railway operation and consolidation could be achieved through a bidding process and operation by the (or possibly a number) of franchisees after bidding is complete” (p. 79). Chadwick’s characteristic competition “for the field” solution through franchise bidding appears elsewhere as well and is elaborated by the authors in a separate chapter.
Regulation of Markets” and “Law, Sociology, and Economics,” structure the discussions of the numerous areas to which Chadwick applied his economic analysis. His contributions in the areas of competitive bidding for exclusive contracts, the railways, funeral and burial markets, education, business cycles, criminal justice, sanitation and others are reviewed in turn. The final chapter offers the authors’ reflections on Chadwick’s relevance for contemporary society.
Ekelund and Price argue throughout that “cases and abstractions from the writings of Edwin Chadwick show that ... he brought modern economics to the table in evaluating markets, public policy, and (what he believed to be) the appropriate division of roles between government and the private sector” (p. 45). Although this statement provokes ruminations about what “modern”
subsumes and what it means for an eighteenth-century writer to be so, the authors do not indulge these. They apply modernity to mean Chadwick’s “use of concepts such as the ‘common pool,’ time and opportunity costs, the demand curve, marginal analysis, strategic behavior, public choice, implicit markets (as for ‘accidents’), property rights and liability assignment” (p. 45). An additional aspect of the authors’ claim is Chadwick’s marshaling of statistics to support his recommendations: “Chadwick stands out as a pioneer in the science that requires evidence for reasoning and conclusions regarding economic and social policy” (p. 44). The chapter detailing Chadwick’s analysis of the railways provides an illustrative example. Chadwick contended that the rail system of England was fraught with inefficiencies, such as monopoly, fragmentation, and waste, and supported nationalization. In making this argument, he offered statistics that compared costs and performance across six European countries which showed prices and the degree of price discrimination in England to be the highest. “According to Chadwick, railway operation and consolidation could be achieved through a bidding process and operation by the (or possibly a number) of franchisees after bidding is complete” (p. 79). Chadwick’s characteristic competition “for the field” solution through franchise bidding appears elsewhere as well and is elaborated by the authors in a separate chapter.
Ekelund and Price do an excellent
job of contextualizing Chadwick’s arguments
regarding the railways by comparing them with the opinions of William Galt, Jules upuit, and A.T. Hadley
and through examining his exchange with
John Stuart Mill. Galt, like Chadwick, also advocated nationalization, though he supported the
operation of the railways by the government.
In contrast, Dupuit and Hadley had more optimistic perspectives on open competition. A letter by Mill to
Chadwick in 1864 captures the debate:
“About the economical advantage, touched upon in your letter, of a consolidation of railways, you are not likely
to find any help in the French
economists. They are, nearly all of them, more hostile to consolidation and to government action that I am; and I am more so than you” (quoted on p. 88).
economists. They are, nearly all of them, more hostile to consolidation and to government action that I am; and I am more so than you” (quoted on p. 88).
Chadwick’s analyses of criminal
justice and sanitation in England display
particular sophistication. Chadwick identified rent-seeking, free riding, common pool resources, and asymmetric information as systemic inefficiencies that a proposed reform must remedy. Although his insights do bear strong resemblances to familiar modern counterparts, the weakest aspect of the book is the intimation of relation without probing for genetic links. Taking the
novelty of Chadwick seriously in areas like market failure needs an account that dialogues with the traditional narrative or the reader is left to wonder why and how such a prescient thinker became neglected by his antecessors. Moreover, the exercise of evaluating the veracity of Chadwick’s economics from the viewpoint of the matured doctrines inclines too many passages to the curious hobbyists’ – as opposed to the historians’ – interest.
particular sophistication. Chadwick identified rent-seeking, free riding, common pool resources, and asymmetric information as systemic inefficiencies that a proposed reform must remedy. Although his insights do bear strong resemblances to familiar modern counterparts, the weakest aspect of the book is the intimation of relation without probing for genetic links. Taking the
novelty of Chadwick seriously in areas like market failure needs an account that dialogues with the traditional narrative or the reader is left to wonder why and how such a prescient thinker became neglected by his antecessors. Moreover, the exercise of evaluating the veracity of Chadwick’s economics from the viewpoint of the matured doctrines inclines too many passages to the curious hobbyists’ – as opposed to the historians’ – interest.
In their concluding appraisal,
Ekelund and Price suggest Chadwick’s modernity
in a third sense: “Economic theory is one thing – the world as it actually exists is another. This might be
the mantra of Edwin Chadwick as it is
for most policymakers in all countries today” (p. 216). In other words, Chadwick was keenly aware of the
constraints and rade-offs that must be
faced when crafting policy. “As such Chadwick originated a popular notion in the economics of regulation and
institutions – that no state of the
world is nirvana, and that, before committing societal resource to use, all feasible alternatives must be examined”
(p. 178). In the effort to apply
economics in weighing costs and benefits, Chadwick’s struggles, at least, are undoubtedly modern.”
Copyright (c) 2013 by EH.Net. All
rights reserved. This work may be copied
for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to the author
and the list. For other permission, please
contact the EH.Net Administrator (administrator@eh.net).
Published by EH.Net (April 2013). All EH.Net reviews are archived at http://www.eh.net/BookReview