Libros: ¿Instituciones o geografía?: Distant Tyranny: Markets, Power, and Backwardness in Spain, 1650-1800

Regina Grafe, /Distant Tyranny: Markets, Power, and Backwardness in Spain,  1650-1800/. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2012. xvii + 291 pp., ISBN 978-0-691-14484-9.

La reseña para EH.Net de  Mauricio Drelichman, profesor asociado del Departmento de Economía de la Universidad de British Columbia, participantes en el programa de instituciones, organizaciones y crecimiento del CIFAR (Canadian Institute for Advanced Research) y autor de numerosos artículos sobre la historia institucional y financiera de la España  moderna temprana, señala: " Spain has long been a thorn in the side of economic historians. In the  sixteenth century, it was richer and politically more advanced than virtually  all its European peers. At the beginning of the seventeenth it ruled the  largest empire that had yet existed, while giving the world masterpieces of  art and literature. Ever since, searching for the roots of the long  “decline” that ensued has been the single-minded quest of political commentators and historians of Spain alike. With /Distant Tyranny/, Regina  Grafe may well have put this entire group out of a job.

A large, if relatively recent, literature has established that Spain did not  quite stagnate after 1600, and certainly did not decline. It nonetheless grew  at a substantially slower pace than the European norm, and hence fell  steadily through the ranks of Western economic powers. Economists in the New Institutional Economics tradition pinned the blame for this on a predatory,  absolutist state and its extractive institutions. Historians, on their part,  have often pointed at the “tyranny of distance” – Spain’s famously  tortuous geography and difficult communications – as the main culprit for  its economic underperformance. 


To take on both the NIE and the geographic traditions, Grafe enlists the help  of an unlikely ally: salt cod, or /bacalao/, as it is still known in Spain.  By the seventeenth century cod was a staple food in Spain, and the trade  imbalance it represented was a continuous source of worry to mercantilist  minds. Traditional studies of market integration have relied almost  exclusively on grain prices. Grain markets, however, were characterized by  heavy intervention from local governments to guarantee bread supplies. Cod  was free from any such distortions, while ubiquitous enough to serve as a  benchmark good. Chapter 3 explores the production technology, trade  mechanisms, internal distribution, and the cultural and biological bases of  cod demand. The result is a strong case that cod can indeed be used to trace  and characterize the behavior of markets across Spain. 

Data in hand, Grafe proceeds to evaluate the tyranny of distance argument.  That Spanish markets were not integrated across different regions is a  well-known result. What is new – and striking – is that the lack of  integration is almost completely uncorrelated with distance and transport  costs. These were indeed formidable obstacles, but progress was being  steadily made in improving road links and reducing travel times. More  importantly, when the price of North American cod in the Atlantic port of  Seville was 40% higher than in far inland Madrid, long distances and poor  transport seem the wrong places to look for an explanation.

Chapters 5 and 6 deliver the central thesis of the book. The roots of  Spain’s lack of integration –and the backwardness that ultimately  resulted from it– are traced to the extreme jurisdictional fragmentation  that afflicted the peninsula. The first indictment is handed to Spain’s  “historic territories” – roughly corresponding to the medieval  predecessor states – which persisted in the form of separate kingdoms until  the eighteenth century, and much longer as differentiated fiscal and  political institutions. Next, the “urban republics” – the cities as  seats of economic and political power – take their share of the blame. Both  territories and cities had inherited old “freedoms”. These consisted in  exemptions from royal taxation and the ability to maintain differentiated  fiscal regimes, resulting in large distortions and formidable barriers to  trade. Cities and territories were able to push back on each and every  attempt of the monarchy to streamline and rationalize the system. Their success evidenced how little power the supposedly “absolutist” Habsburg  and Bourbon dynasties really had. While kings were expected to serve as  arbiters and mediators, urban and regional elites severely curtailed the  power of any monarch that tried to engage in meaningful state-building. In  one telling example, the crown strove to harmonize the tobacco monopoly –  one of its most profitable revenue streams – across the country. While  dutifully implemented in Castile, the historic heartland of Spain, the tax  was strongly resisted in some territories and lackadaisically enforced in  others. The kingdom of Navarre dismissed it outright, arguing that its own  monopoly predated the Crown’s. In order to maintain consistency across tax  rates and internal borders, and unable to force a unified fiscal  implementation, the king of Spain was forced to become the tax farmer of the  Navarrese tobacco monopoly – a monarch reduced to serving as a contractor  of one of its own domains.

There is little to quibble with in Grafe’s work. The early chapters build a  solid foundation, based on detailed archival research and a meticulous  tracing of market behavior. As the focus shifts to broader issues of  political economy, the weight of the argument comes to rest on a tightly  woven historical narrative and a brilliant command of a literature as  unwieldy as any. When applied to an issue as weighty as the long-run  underperformance of Spain, one cannot help but admire the combination of a  detailed, erudite analysis with a coherent macro-historical logic. If one  area for improvement were to be found, it would be on the comparative aspect. 

While the centralist French experience is consistently brought up as the  mirror image of Spain, perhaps Germany, with its large jurisdictional  fragmentation but very different political and economic trajectories, might  have provided a more interesting counterpoint.

When combined with the weakness of the central state, the hodgepodge of  privileges, exemptions, and other “freedoms” of Spanish territories and  cities resulted in a system that preserved the special interests of local  elites at the expense of consumers – and, ultimately, of long-run growth.  Whenever kings tried to strengthen their position, revolts and secession  ensued. Monarchs used repression sparingly, and always accompanied it with a relaxation of the offending policies. The paradigm of a weak center and  strong regions survived throughout the old regime, becoming a headache for  the Napoleonic invaders, and only retreating in the twentieth century under  the extraordinary violence brought about by the Civil War. However, as these  lines are written, nearly two million people fill the streets of Barcelona  clamoring for Catalan independence. In a rare feat for an economic history  book, /Distant Tyranny/ may yet shed as much light on current events as it  does on the past."

Copyright (c) 2012 by EH.Net. All rights reserved.