Dora
L. Costa y Naomi R. Lamoreaux, han editado
/Understanding Long-Run Economic Growth:
Geography, Institutions, and the Knowledge Economy/. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, ISBN: 978-0-226-11634-1. que
ha sido reseñado para EH.Net por Howard
Bodenhorn, del Departamento de Economía de la Clemson University.
Bodenhorn
comenta “Economic history lost one of its best and brightest with Ken
Sokoloff’s death in May 2007. To
celebrate and commemorate his contributions to
economics, Dora Costa and Naomi Lamoreaux collected an impressive and
diverse group of essays contributed by
Ken’s friends, colleagues, coauthors, and
classmates. Ken’s interests were wide-ranging – he wrote on early industrialization and heights and health, but
his signal contributions concerned
invention and innovation, as well as the complex connections between geography, institutions and long-run
economic growth. Fittingly, the essays
are equally wide ranging.
The
first article is an essay Ken was working on with Stan Engerman and advances the initial
conditions-geography-institutions approach explored in their earlier research. The central argument
is that differences in initial conditions
between North America and Central and South America set those regions on markedly different social,
economic and political trajectories. With
its relative shortage of indigenous labor, early settlers recognized that North America would prosper only through
European settlement and they adopted
institutions in which new arrivals were welcomed (eventually) into the polity and might, with good fortune and
hard work, rise in society. Blessed with
an abundance of indigenous workers, the earliest settlers in South and Central America adopted
institutions that discouraged European immigration
by restricting economic and political privilege. Moreover, the nature of staple crop production pushed the
returns to unskilled labor so low that
few Europeans came. The argument, briefly stated, is that early inequality begat later inequality through
endogenously arising institutions that
favored the few, the elite.
Sokoloff
and Engerman’s research raises fundamental questions: Are institutions exogenously determined by
idiosyncratic events, such as the arrival
of British rather than Spanish colonizers, as the legal origins approach posits?[1] Are institutions, once established,
persistent, as the colonial origins
approach contends?[2] Or, are
institutions endogenous to geographies
as societies struggle with how best to deal with the challenges of environments, technologies, and factor
endowments? Sokoloff and Engerman are
clearly in the endogenous institutions camp. It is fitting, then, that the next
two articles take on the exogeneity/endogeneity
debate from alternative perspectives. Camilo
Garcia-Jimeno and James A. Robinson explore the long-run implications of
Frederick Jackson Turner’s thesis that the American frontier shaped its egalitarian representative democracy.
Garcia-Jimeno and Robinson recognize that
the U.S. was not the only New World country with a frontier and offer the “conditional frontier hypothesis,” which
posits that the consequences of the
frontier are conditional on the existing political equilibrium when settlement of the frontier commences. They
consider 21 New World countries and,
from a series of regressions, conclude that if political institutions were bad at the outset (which they define as
1850) the existence of a frontier may have
made them worse. The oligarchs divvied up the frontier among themselves, which further entrenched
their economic and political power.
Exogenous institutions rule.
Or do
they? Stephen Haber next explores banking and finance in three countries – the U.S., Mexico and Brazil – but
starts from a very different, very
Sokoloff-ian (if I may) perspective. For Haber, as for Sokoloff, the task facing the economic
historian interested in institutions involves
tracing the many and complex ways in which economic and political power becomes embedded in institutions, how
those institutions influence the formation
of competing coalitions, and how competition between them either entrenches or alters the original
institutions. Pursuing these connections is, Haber (p. 90) argues, “a task
better suited to historical narratives than
to econometric hypothesis testing.” What connects banking in these three countries is that the elite used their
existing power to rent seek – to elicit
government sanction of limited entry and privileged monopoly. What separated the three countries was that rent
seeking efforts largely failed in the
U.S. If Jackson’s war on the Second Bank was emblematic of anything it was that U.S. populists had little tolerance for
government-sanctioned economic
privilege. Haber doesn’t, and I doubt that Ken would, attribute the Jacksonian attitude to an accident of
history. It was organically, indelibly
American. Joel Mokyr summarizes Ken’s approach to his other great intellectual passion: invention and innovation. Innovation
was the consequence of purposive,
rational behavior. Inventors, at least at some level, were motivated and directed by costs and benefits.
Ken also recognized that inventive
activity was sensitive to the institutions that generated markets that defined the rewards for innovation.
Zorina Khan takes these issues head on
in her analysis of patents versus prizes. At the risk of gross oversimplification,
the English and the French preferred prizes for
inventions believing that what motivated inventive genius was the esteem
of one’s peers. Americans proceeded
under the pragmatic and republican belief
that profits motivated and markets would “allow society to better
realize its potential” (p. 207). Prizes
were subject to momentary whims, were idiosyncratic,
difficult to predict, and therefore less useful in pushing out the frontiers of
useful knowledge. Markets elicited more innovation, at least as markets were organized in America.
The
second article in the volume to which Ken directly contributed is coauthored with Naomi Lamoreaux and Dhanoos
Sutthiphisal. They, too, explore the
connection between markets and inventions in the “new economy” of the 1920s. They argue that the rapid expansion of
equity markets afforded many small
enterprises on the technological frontier access to finance that was unavailable a generation earlier. Big firms
dominated patenting in the Northeast. In
what became the Rust Belt, small, entrepreneurial firms with new products or processes issued equities or
attracted the venture capital necessary
for them to bring their products to market. Markets influence innovation in all kinds of direct and
indirect ways. The constraints of a book review, unfortunately, preclude a
discussion of the many other very good
essays in the volume but which venture so far afield that they are not readily condensed. They are
all worth reading; I was particularly
fascinated by Dan Bogart and John Majewski’s article comparing the British and American transportation
revolutions, and touched by Manuel Trajtenberg’s
reflections on Ken as scholar and friend. On a personal note, I am a
beneficiary of Ken’s gentle but firm guidance.
It was inadvertently revealed to me that Ken was one of the
anonymous reviewers of my /State Banking
in Early America/ (2003). While the manuscript
was well outside his research interests, he offered several
insightful comments, one of which forced
me to think more deeply about a central idea.
My book is better for Ken’s advice. Many of the chapters included in
this volume are undoubtedly better for
Ken’s prodding, pushing and provocation.
He is missed.”
Notes:
1. See, for example, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1998. “Law and Finance.” /Journal of Political Economy/ 106(6). 2. See, for example, Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson. 2001. “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development.” /American Economic Review/ 91(4).
Copyright
(c) 2013 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be copied for non-profit educational uses if proper
credit is given to the author and the
list.